Risk-Neutral Pricing of Options post-Black Scholes
From Cox and Ross to Harrison and Kreps
The use of options has been going on for millennia. The first recorded instance dates back to Thales of Miletus, born around 650 B.C. Thales was known as a philosopher, scientist and mathematician, and was “the first person to investigate the basic principles, the question of the originating substances of matter and, therefore, as the founder of the school of natural philosophy.”[1] During the lifetime of Thales, Miletus was densely populated with groves of olive trees. Consequently, there was a thriving trade in olives and olive byproducts. In his book “Politics” (published around 1259), Aristotle wrote: “Somehow, through observation of the heavenly bodies, Thales concluded that there would be a bumper crop of olives. He raised the money to put a deposit on the olive presses of Miletus and Chios, so that when the harvest was ready, he was able to let them out at a rate which brought him considerable profit.” Thales did not purchase the presses outright. By placing a small deposit on them, he was able to control the rights to them, reaping a profit for a relatively small investment. Had the olive harvest not come in as expected, Thales would have lost only his deposit. Clearly the value of the rights to lease the presses was highly dependent on the prospects of the olive crop. This was the first recorded example of a call option: the right, but not the obligation, to control an underlying asset at some future time.
Another documented example of early options trading was the tulip mania[2] of the 1630s. Tulips were introduced to Holland in the 17th century for study as a medicinal agent. During the Dutch Golden Age, the flowers became symbols of status and luxury and a booming trade developed[3]. Botanists developed many variants of the basic tulip. Certain hybrids and mutations they developed were highly coveted. The Semper Augustus, a flower with vivid red and white striped petals, was “famous for being the most expensive tulip sold during tulip mania.” 2,3The stripes were found to be the result of a tulip virus and professional growers began bidding up the prices for bulbs containing this virus. Tulips can be grown from either seeds or bulbs. Tulips bloom in the spring, and produce clone bulbs as well as several buds. After blooming, tulip bulbs can be uprooted during the period June through September. A vigorous spot market developed for trading these bulbs. During the off-season, trading continued through the use of futures contracts, which obligated the buyer to purchase. Tulip prices were driven up to dizzying heights. The high prices attracted speculators, who drove the price even higher, creating a speculative bubble. At the peak of the bubble, tulip contracts could cost as much as a house, and the bulb of one rare variant, the Viceroy, is reported to have “cost between 3000 and 4200 florins depending on size. A skilled craftsman at the time earned about 300 florins a year.”[4] Eventually the prices plunged, ruining many investors who found that there was no longer a market for tulips. “Some were left holding contracts to purchase tulips at prices now ten times greater than those on the open market, while others found themselves in possession of bulbs now worth a fraction of the price they had paid.”
In 1637 the Dutch
Parliament “announced that all
futures contracts written after November 30, 1636 and before the re-opening of
the cash market in the early Spring, were to be interpreted as option
contracts.” (2) This meant that the futures buyers were no
longer obligated to buy tulips if they didn’t wish to. Instead, they could get out of the contract
by simply compensating “the sellers with
a small fixed percentage of the contract price”, which worked out to about
1/30th of the contract price. This
action transformed futures contracts on tulips into call options on tulips. Of
course, this only increased speculation as the potential profit was virtually
unlimited, while the downside risk was limited to the premium paid. What should the fair price for a tulip or
olive option be? The answer to this question was found hundreds of years after
the Dutch tulip mania, and derivatives pricing continues to be an active field
of research today.

A derivative is a financial claim whose value is derived from the value of an underlying asset or contract. A gold futures contract is a derivative that depends on the underlying value of gold while an option on a Eurodollar Futures contract depends on the value of the underlying Eurodollar Futures contract. Derivatives are also referred to as contingent claims. Derivatives range from a simple forward contract to highly complex options that depend on the price history of the underlying asset. Derivatives can be purchased on exchanges or custom-tailored to the parties needs as OTC transactions. Derivatives exist to enable market participants to transfer risk, to take a position or to exploit mispricing in a market. There are three major classes of market participants: hedgers, speculators and arbitrageurs. Market participants wishing to transfer risk are called hedgers. They generally do not take a view on markets. Those participants taking a view in the market are called speculators. The third category, arbitrageurs, exploits profit opportunities that may arise from a variety of reasons. Derivatives play a vital and crucial role in capital markets.[5]
A derivative on an underlying asset, for example a stock or a stock index, is known as an option. Options are traded on Eurodollar futures contracts, commodities, foreign exchange rates, interest rates and so on. Options are similar in some ways to forwards and futures but significantly different in others. In contrast to futures and forwards, it costs money upfront to buy an option. This cost is called the option premium. The buyer of the option has the right but not the obligation to exercise the option while the seller of the option is obligated to perform. This is unlike the forward contract where, once entered, both parties are obligated to deliver.
Options are traded on most major exchanges. They are used for hedging purposes, for speculation and by arbitrageurs. A speculator is an investor who wishes to take a position on a particular asset without actually owning the asset. Since options on an underlying can be purchased at a fraction of the cost it would take to acquire a long position in the underlying, options provide leverage. Leverage magnifies the returns, both positive and negative, which is the reason that some people say that options are very risky. Options range from the very simple, “plain vanilla” flavors such as simple puts and calls on a stock, to the very exotic such as binary options, barrier options, Asian options, compound options and so forth. The value of such exotic options depends not just on the value of the underlying at expiry, but on the price path over the entire time period. There are options on currencies, options on interest rates, options on futures, options on swaps and even options on options.
In contrast, with options a price or level (the strike) is specified in advance along with an expiration time. In order to model the behavior of the option, we require a model governing the dynamics of the underlying asset. The model for the movement of the underlying asset is fairly complicated and is known as the Black-Scholes partial differential equation. The model, with modifications, can be applied to interest rates, stock indices, FX contracts and certain other options as well. Before we can address the Black Scholes equation, however, we should start with the building blocks which were established by Bachelier.
Bachelier In 1900, a French doctoral student named Bachelier defended his thesis, “Théorie de la Spéculation.” His dissertation is lauded as the beginning of financial economics, and many important results were developed in this paper. Bachelier was thought to have had some experience with to the French stock market while working there prior to earning his doctorate. In the course of his studies he studied subjects including probability and heat transfer. His dissertation covered the movements of stocks from a probabilistic point of view. “La détermination de ces mouvements se subordonne à un nombre infini de facteurs: il est dès lors impossible d’en espérer la prévision mathématique… Mais il est possible d’étudier matheématiquement l’état statique du marché à un instant donné, c’est-à-dire d’établir la loi de probabilité des variations de cours qu’admet à cet instant le marché. Si le marché, en effect, ne prévoit pas les mouvements, il les considére comme étant plus ou moins probables, et cette probabilité peut s’évaluer mathématiquement.“[6] He modeled the fluctuation of stock prices with a random walk process, which he was familiar with from his study of thermal sciences. He hypothesized that over a short time interval, price fluctuations should be independent of the current value, also, that the price fluctuations were independent of the past values. With the goal of valuing options, he described the distribution of the resulting stock prices, and solved for the probability that the price would exceed or fall below a certain level. Bachelier even included diagrams of call option payoffs in his dissertation, as shown below.

Bachelier assumed that stock prices followed a normal distribution and made the argument that in equilibrium, there would be as many buyers believing that the price would rise as there were sellers believing that the price would fall, and given this, the probability that the stock would move up must be about the same probability that the stock would move down. As such, market participants would expect to make zero profit, and the market was a “fair game.” This is the foundation of what is known today as a martingale. By applying the memorylessness property of the stock price process, he also developed what is known today as the homogeneous Chapman-Kolmogorov equation. Bachelier assumed that the process followed by the stock was given by
where sigma represented the volatility of the stock price. He also predicted that the volatility would increase accordingly with the square root of time, an important concept still used today. Bachelier “normalized” his volatility by defining the quantity H (which he referred to as “the nervousness” of the underlying stock price S[1]) as
[1] http://www.math.ethz.ch/~jteichma/finalversion071108.pdf
With this definition, the price of a call option under his model included the factor
Assuming Brownian motion, his formula for the valuation of a call option was based on the Fourier equation of transient one-dimensional heat transfer,
His equation for valuation of a call was:
where N' denotes the probability density function of the normal distribution,
Bachelier’s pioneering work formed the foundation for the important Ito calculus that would follow years later as well as the work of Fischer Black and Myron Scholes. Other authors criticized his assumption of the normal distribution, which permitted negative asset prices, and the fact that he assumed zero interest rates (no time value of money, which implies zero risk aversion.) These assumptions did not prevent option prices from exceeding the price of the underlying asset, which was problematic as the underlying asset price is an upper bound for the option. In 1964 a researched named Case Sprenkle extended Bachelier’s ideas by assuming that stock prices following a log normal distribution. This corrected the problem of potentially negative prices. Sprenkle also included a drift in Bachelier’s random walk and allowed for risk aversion. His resulting formulation of the call price was[4]
Sprenkle described Z as a discount factor dependent on the risk of the stock, and r as
“the ratio of the expected value of the stock price at the time the warrant matures to the current stock price”, and “he tries to estimate the values … empirically, but finds that he is unable to do so.”[1] Many of the derivations preceding Black Scholes shared the concept that if one knew the terminal probability distribution, the option could easily be valued by discounting at the appropriate rate. However, the appropriate discount rate to use was not clear.
Black and Scholes In 1958 and 1961, Modigliani and Miller (“M & M”) published their famed propositions related to the value of a firm. The underlying accounting identity was that the value of a firm’s assets A was comprised of the sum of the value of the firm’s liabilities L and the shareholder’s equity E. In valuing the equity, M&M noted that equity holders essentially own a call option on the assets of the firm: if the value of the firm assets exceeded the value of the liabilities, the equity holders were entitled to the residual, however, if the firm value was below the value of the firm’s liabilities, the shareholders would be wiped out.
Thus, E = (A-L,0)+. There were many open questions regarding not just the valuation of corporate liabilities, which was difficult due to the non-observable default risk, but in the proper value of shareholder’s equity. Many researchers tackled the problem, including Edward Thorpe, Case Sprenkle, Jack Treynor and Fischer Black and Myron Scholes.
In their celebrated 1973 paper, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities”, Black and Scholes noted that Sprenkle’s (among other contributors) valuation formula was incomplete due to the presence of the arbitrary parameters Z and r. Black and Scholes recognized that the option price was related to the price of the underlying stock, noting that the volatility of the option would in general not be a constant but would depend jointly on the stock price and time to maturity. They extended the hedging previous work of Thorpe and Kassouf and constructed an equilibrium hedge in which the expected return on the hedged position had to be equal to the return on a risk free asset. They used an arbitrage argument in the derivation.
The Black-Scholes Equation
Many models of asset behavior assume that the asset follows some form of random walk. The Wiener process is often used to model this behavior. It supposes that the asset price behaves something like a particle that is impacted by a number of small shocks. In physics this behavior is referred to as Brownian motion. Modeling the percentage change in stock price over a small period of time, the process is given as:
to be continued....
Footnotes
[1] “Thales of Miletus – A Compendium of Articles”, http://www.martinfrost.ws/htmlfiles/thales1.html, quoting Aristotle on Thales, also http://www.optiontradingpedia.com/history_of_options_trading.htm
[2] http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Tulip_mania
[3] http://www.holland.nl/uk/holland/sights/tulips-history.html
[4] http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Tulip_mania
[5] Jennifer Voitle, “Quantitative Finance Interview Questions”, chapter 5
[6]http://archive.numdam.org/ARCHIVE/ASENS/ASENS_1900_3_17_/ASENS_1900_3_17__21_0/ASENS_1900_3_17__21_0.pdf, translated as “The determination of these movements is subordinated to an infinite number of factors: it is therefore impossible to expect the mathematical prediction ... But it is possible to study mathematically the static state of the market at a given moment, that is to establish the probability of fluctuations admits at this point the market. If the market, in effect, does not provide the movement, he sees them as more or less likely, and this probability can be evaluated mathematically”, google translator
[7] http://www.math.ethz.ch/~jteichma/finalversion071108.pdf
[8] Charles Smithson, “Wonderful Life”, Class Notes, Risk Magazine
[9] F. Black and M. Scholes, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities”, 1973
[10] Fischer Black later stated (1988) that, “A key part of the option paper I wrote with Myron Scholes was the arbitrage argument for deriving the formula. Bob [Robert Merton] gave us that argument. It should probably be called the Black-Merton-Scholes paper.''
[11] Peter Carr “A Practitioner’s Guide to Mathematical Finance”, http://www.pstat.ucsb.edu/crfms/inaugural%20slide/Peter-Carr.pdf
[12] Note that Cox and Ross use the symbol S for the asset price, rather than x as Black and Scholes used.
[13] MARK FISHER AND CHRISTIAN GILLES, “AN ANALYSIS OF THE DOUBLING STRATEGY: THE COUNTABLE CASE”, http://www.markfisher.net/~mefisher/papers/countable_doubling_strategy.pdf
References
- J. Michael Harrison and David M. Kreps, “Martingales and Arbitrage in Multiperiod Securities Markets”,
- Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes, The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, 81 (May-June 1973), 637-659
- Cox, John C and Stephen A Ross, The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes, Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (January-March 1976), 145-166
- Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller,"The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment," American Economic Review, ]une 1958, 48, No. 3, pp. 261-297
- “A PRIMER IN FINANCIAL ECONOMICS”, By S. F. Whelan, D. C. Bowie and A. J. Hibbert, http://www.soa.org/files/pdf/prime.pdf
- “In Honor of the Nobel Laureates: Robert C. Merton and Myron S.Scholes: A Partial Differential Equation That Changed the World”, Robert A. Jarrow http://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/jep.13.4.229 Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 13, Number 4—Fall 1999—Pages 229–248
- Mark Rubenstein, A History of The Theory of Investments
Recently
Leave a Reply
You must be logged in to post a comment.